If there are premia to be enjoyed by dividing a stock's return stream
into its component parts, why is it that corporations do not issue the
component parts? Since a portfolio of one prime and one score replica
tes the cash flows from one share of stock, we might expect the sum of
the prime and score prices to equal the stock price. In fact, the sum
of the prime and score prices significantly exceeds the underlying st
ock price. In frictionless markets, this premium presents an arbitrage
opportunity: investors will buy the stock and short the prime and the
score. In an incomplete market and/or a market with frictions, the un
bundling of cash flows could be valuable to investors. In issuing the
component parts, corporations can reduce their cost of capital. Transa
ctions costs are one possible explanation of the premium addressed in
this paper. Another explanation is taxes, which is the focus of this p
aper. Our hypothesis is that if investors face different tax rules, th
ey will usually disagree on the value of derivative securities relativ
e to the price of an underlying security. Furthermore, each tax-bracke
t clientele will purchase those derivative securities it values most h
ighly. In doing so, the clientele determines the market price of those
derivatives. For any one tax bracket, the sum of the score and prime
valuations must add up to the price of the stock. However, this equali
ty need not hold for market prices when the score's price is determine
d by one tax bracket and the prime's price by another. Primes and scor
es provide a controlled experiment concerning tax effects. First, comp
any-specific information should affect derivative securities, such as
primes and scores, only through the observable stock price. Second, pr
ecise predictions can be made about the size of the tax effects. Third
, because primes and scores were relatively long-term and illiquid sec
urities, arbitraging away tax-driven valuation differences might well
have been prohibitively costly. Therefore, our study has important imp
lications concerning tax clienteles and their effect on price that goe
s beyond the pricing of primes and scores, and can be generalized to m
any situations where taxes and tax clienteles may affect prices. Our m
ain conclusion is that both transactions costs and tax clientele effec
ts are too small to explain the observed premia, even when synchronous
prices are used instead of closing prices. In addition, we show that
scores should be held and priced by tax-exempt investors while primes
should be held and priced by investors in the highest tax bracket. Las
tly, primes are relatively well priced by the Black-Scholes model. Thi
s implies that most of the ''mispricing'' is due to the score. To exam
ine whether tax clienteles are responsible for score and prime premia,
we first identified which of three extreme tax classes will hold the
scores and which will hold the primes. These tax classes are tax-exemp
t, individuals, and corporations. We compare the market prices of scor
es to their valuations by tax-exempt investors, by individuals, and by
corporations. Under the tax-clientele prediction, scores should refle
ct the valuation of tax-exempt investors.The empirical evidence as a w
hole cannot be taken to support the tax-clientele hypothesis. We repea
t this analysis for the primes. Despite the close fit with market pric
es, the evidence does not support the prediction that corporate invest
ors or individuals in the highest tax bracket hold and price the prime
s. Under the transaction cost/market completion hypothesis, investors
should value scores above their replication values because market fric
tions do not easily allow such replication. Therefore, the Black-Schol
es model should underestimate score prices. The transaction data for 2
6 scores show that the Black-Scholes model underestimates, on average,
in only 12 cases. Thus, these data provide some evidence against the
transaction cost/market completion hypothesis as well. The question re
mains as to whether the premium represents an arbitrage opportunity th
at was not eliminated due to institutional factors or unfamiliarity wi
th the market. Market frictions and the limited supply of arbitrage ca
pital may provide some of the explanation for these results. A small m
arket can produce ''incorrect'' prices because it does not provide suf
ficient opportunities for arbitrageurs. Investors knew that the size o
f the market would not increase because of the change in the tax law.
In fact, they knew that the market would not exist beyond five years,
at the most. It is possible that if the market had been given the oppo
rtunity to grow, more arbitrage capital would have become available an
d the premium would have decreased with time.