Political discrimination has often pushed the domestic value of agricu
lture in developing countries below its value in markets at the border
. This paper seeks to explain the reasons why border prices themselves
undervalue the linkages that agriculture has to economic growth in th
e early stages of development. If agriculture is critically important
to stimulating and sustaining rapid economic growth, those countries t
hat fail to correct this discrimination exact a heavy toll in economic
performance. Furthermore, the poorest countries will suffer the most.
Agricultural development and development of the non-agricultural econ
omy are closely linked. The traditional market-mediated linkages form
the core of economic analysis of the role of agriculture in economic d
evelopment: providing labour for an industrial work-force, food for an
expanding population with higher incomes, savings for industrial inve
stments, markets for industrial output, export earnings to pay for imp
orted capital goods, and raw materials for agro-processing industries.
A second category of linkages is not well mediated by market forces,
even when markets are working well. The impact of agricultural growth
on the rest of the economy through non-market linkages can be traced u
sing a simple growth-accounting framework that examines contributions
to the labour force, capital investment and the productivity with whic
h these two physical factors are utilised. Several linkages stand out
as likely to be important and potentially measurable because they draw
on the efficiency of decision making in rural households, the low opp
ortunity cost of their labour resources, the opportunity for farm inve
stment without financial intermediaries, the potential to earn high ra
tes of return on public investments that correct for urban bias, the c
ontribution of food price stability to increased efficiency in investm
ent decisions, and the impact of growth in food production on widespre
ad improvement in nutrient intake and labour productivity. Each of the
se factors alone, as public investment and favourable policy stimulate
growth in the agricultural sector, should cause an increase in the ef
ficiency of resource allocation and thus higher total factor productiv
ity. Several of these mechanisms will also serve to speed factor accum
ulation by increasing the savings rate or improving factor mobility.